亚色在线观看_亚洲人成a片高清在线观看不卡_亚洲中文无码亚洲人成频_免费在线黄片,69精品视频九九精品视频,美女大黄三级,人人干人人g,全新av网站每日更新播放,亚洲三及片,wwww无码视频,亚洲中文字幕无码一区在线

立即打開(kāi)
《財(cái)富》獨(dú)家對(duì)話(huà)中國(guó)經(jīng)濟(jì)唱衰者

《財(cái)富》獨(dú)家對(duì)話(huà)中國(guó)經(jīng)濟(jì)唱衰者

Chris Matthews 2016-02-14
真正讓人震驚的是,在創(chuàng)造增長(zhǎng)奇跡期間,,首先是增長(zhǎng)率確實(shí)居高不下,,高得令人震驚,然后在調(diào)整期增速迅速放緩,,快得也讓人大吃一驚,。沒(méi)有經(jīng)濟(jì)體能例外,始終如此,。崛起之猛和隕落之快都令人大跌眼鏡,。

2012年,,國(guó)際油價(jià)還盤(pán)桓在每桶100美元的高價(jià),中國(guó)GDP增速還處在10%以上的高速上,。那時(shí),,你很難會(huì)想到跟誰(shuí)預(yù)測(cè)中國(guó)經(jīng)濟(jì)會(huì)出現(xiàn)滑坡,導(dǎo)致大宗商品價(jià)格崩潰的,,最終令全球陷入衰退,。

除非有人一直在看邁克爾·佩蒂斯寫(xiě)的文章。佩蒂斯曾在華爾街做交易員,,現(xiàn)任北京大學(xué)光華管理學(xué)院金融學(xué)教授,。這些年,他一直在警告中國(guó)經(jīng)濟(jì)增長(zhǎng)越來(lái)越失衡,。早在2012年,,他就預(yù)測(cè)大宗商品價(jià)格會(huì)崩盤(pán)。

佩蒂斯認(rèn)為,,中國(guó)經(jīng)濟(jì)正在重蹈許多國(guó)家的覆轍,,比如二戰(zhàn)后的蘇聯(lián)、上世紀(jì)70年代的巴西和80年代的日本,。在這些例子中,,政府通過(guò)出臺(tái)一些人為促進(jìn)投資、抑制消費(fèi)的政策推動(dòng)經(jīng)濟(jì)迅速增長(zhǎng),,也累積了大規(guī)模的國(guó)際貿(mào)易順差,,但最終經(jīng)濟(jì)發(fā)展失衡導(dǎo)致衰退,中國(guó)就正在面臨這個(gè)問(wèn)題,。

《財(cái)富》雜志最近采訪(fǎng)了佩蒂斯,,請(qǐng)他暢想中國(guó)經(jīng)濟(jì)接下來(lái)何去何從,,及其將怎樣影響美國(guó)、乃至全球經(jīng)濟(jì),。以下是此次采訪(fǎng)的主要內(nèi)容,。

《財(cái)富》:你是在什么時(shí)候認(rèn)識(shí)到中國(guó)經(jīng)濟(jì)增長(zhǎng)模式不可持續(xù)的?

佩蒂斯:很早以前,,到2006年就已經(jīng)很明顯了,。

《財(cái)富》:你為什么認(rèn)為,中國(guó)的增長(zhǎng)模式會(huì)和巴西等國(guó)的試驗(yàn)一樣,?

佩蒂斯:經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)家亞歷山大·格申克龍?jiān)岢?,投資驅(qū)動(dòng)的經(jīng)濟(jì)繁榮有兩大基石。首先必須強(qiáng)制推升儲(chǔ)蓄率,,可以通過(guò)限制家庭消費(fèi)實(shí)現(xiàn),;然后必須引導(dǎo)投資過(guò)程??匆豢此型顿Y增長(zhǎng)奇跡的案例,,無(wú)不遵循這種規(guī)律。

真正讓我震驚的是,,在創(chuàng)造增長(zhǎng)奇跡期間,,首先是增長(zhǎng)率確實(shí)居高不下,高得令人震驚,,然后在調(diào)整期增速迅速放緩,快得也讓人大吃一驚,。沒(méi)有經(jīng)濟(jì)體能例外,,始終如此。崛起之猛和隕落之快都令人大跌眼鏡,。

企業(yè)同樣如此,。以曾經(jīng)的天然氣與電力巨頭安然公司就是個(gè)非常典型的例子。安然破產(chǎn)以前經(jīng)歷了驚人的飛速增長(zhǎng),。我認(rèn)為,,在宣告倒閉之前十年里,安然有八年都是美國(guó)最令人仰慕的企業(yè),。然而,,當(dāng)一家公司或者一個(gè)國(guó)家的資產(chǎn)負(fù)債表出現(xiàn)結(jié)構(gòu)錯(cuò)配時(shí),比如,,資產(chǎn)結(jié)構(gòu)非但沒(méi)有對(duì)沖風(fēng)險(xiǎn),,反而增加了波動(dòng)性,那么,,就會(huì)像在穩(wěn)健的資產(chǎn)負(fù)債表上套一層投機(jī)性極強(qiáng)的資產(chǎn)負(fù)債表,。這么做只會(huì)讓財(cái)務(wù)基礎(chǔ)惡化,。

這就好比股市里賭上全部身家的股民。股市上揚(yáng)時(shí),,這些股民比其他投資者斬獲的收益多,,于是大家開(kāi)始認(rèn)為他們是投資天才。然而,,當(dāng)股市下挫時(shí),,他們會(huì)陪得一干二凈。在我看來(lái),,上述創(chuàng)造奇跡的經(jīng)濟(jì)體和這種投機(jī)者的做法極為相似,。這些經(jīng)濟(jì)體的增速比我們預(yù)計(jì)的快得多,可在一夜之間,,其經(jīng)濟(jì)增長(zhǎng)又會(huì)以不可思議的速度急轉(zhuǎn)直下,。

《財(cái)富》:這些年你一直預(yù)計(jì)大宗商品價(jià)格會(huì)崩潰,而大多數(shù)經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)家認(rèn)為此類(lèi)崩盤(pán)不會(huì)傷害美國(guó)這類(lèi)大經(jīng)濟(jì)體,。為什么他們錯(cuò)了,?

佩蒂斯:在中國(guó)和德國(guó)這樣的經(jīng)濟(jì)體中,存在著較大的貧富收入差距,,家庭收入占全國(guó)GDP的比重很低,。貧富差距對(duì)經(jīng)濟(jì)有同樣影響。貧富差距會(huì)推升儲(chǔ)蓄率,,因?yàn)楦蝗吮绕胀癖姷膬?chǔ)蓄多,。這對(duì)經(jīng)濟(jì)是好事還是壞事?供給學(xué)派經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)家認(rèn)為,,儲(chǔ)蓄率上升總是好的,。凱恩斯主義經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)家則認(rèn)為,必須增加需求,。

事實(shí)上,,這些經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)者都錯(cuò)了,或者說(shuō),,在非常特定的情況下,,他們都是對(duì)的。

在英國(guó),,貧富差距是綿延19世紀(jì)的“大問(wèn)題”,,儲(chǔ)蓄率也一直太高。而在當(dāng)時(shí)的美國(guó),,既可靠又亟需英國(guó)過(guò)剩的儲(chǔ)蓄促進(jìn)生產(chǎn)性投資,。后來(lái),過(guò)剩儲(chǔ)蓄從英國(guó)流向美國(guó),,再后來(lái)英國(guó)人更富有,,美國(guó)人也更有錢(qián)了,。

如果一個(gè)國(guó)家有信用良好的生產(chǎn)性投資項(xiàng)目,卻受制于儲(chǔ)蓄不足,,貧富差距對(duì)經(jīng)濟(jì)就有好處,。可如果沒(méi)有好項(xiàng)目,,就會(huì)出現(xiàn)上世紀(jì)30年代的問(wèn)題,,儲(chǔ)蓄過(guò)剩通過(guò)強(qiáng)迫提高消費(fèi)壓低了中產(chǎn)階級(jí)的儲(chǔ)蓄率,過(guò)剩的儲(chǔ)蓄就會(huì)流入投機(jī)市場(chǎng),,造成股市上漲,、樓市上漲,大家都覺(jué)得自己更有錢(qián)了,,類(lèi)似房地產(chǎn)泡沫期間的感覺(jué),。一旦因?yàn)樨?fù)債累累,投機(jī)游戲被迫終止,,人們不得不不平衡儲(chǔ)蓄與投資,。但是,因?yàn)闊o(wú)人投資,,儲(chǔ)蓄率必然要降低,。降低儲(chǔ)蓄率的方式就是解雇員工。

這就是當(dāng)今世界的現(xiàn)狀,,從大宗商品產(chǎn)業(yè)開(kāi)始,,各行業(yè)都在裁員。美國(guó)前財(cái)長(zhǎng)拉里·薩默斯說(shuō)過(guò),,現(xiàn)在全球最渴望的就是需求,。我覺(jué)得他所言不虛。

《財(cái)富》:你認(rèn)為,,這說(shuō)明全球開(kāi)始步入漫長(zhǎng)的緩慢增長(zhǎng)期?

佩蒂斯:沒(méi)錯(cuò),,我們處于全球增長(zhǎng)疲弱期,,貿(mào)易會(huì)惡化,會(huì)有一波主權(quán)債務(wù)違約事件,。我真正擔(dān)心的是,,歐洲人相當(dāng)不負(fù)責(zé)任。德國(guó)的順差大問(wèn)題首先導(dǎo)致一些歐洲國(guó)家破產(chǎn),,然后向歐洲以外地區(qū)蔓延,。中國(guó)有巨大的貿(mào)易順差,日本也有順差,,還需要擴(kuò)大規(guī)模,。誰(shuí)來(lái)填補(bǔ)這些順差,?過(guò)去幾年,金屬和能源生產(chǎn)國(guó)貿(mào)易逆差規(guī)模擴(kuò)大,,充當(dāng)了“接盤(pán)俠”,。可現(xiàn)在做不到了,。巴西2016年將從上年的貿(mào)易逆差轉(zhuǎn)變?yōu)橘Q(mào)易順差,。全球貿(mào)易格局必會(huì)發(fā)生變化。

用數(shù)學(xué)計(jì)算推測(cè),,只可能出現(xiàn)兩種結(jié)果:要么中國(guó)和歐洲的貿(mào)易順差縮減,,要么其他國(guó)家地區(qū)的貿(mào)易逆差增加。順差增加的通常是最開(kāi)放的經(jīng)濟(jì)體,,一般是允許資本流入的,,例如美國(guó)、加拿大,、澳大利亞和英國(guó),。我最最擔(dān)心的是,如果美國(guó)貿(mào)易逆差飆升,,可能讓國(guó)內(nèi)經(jīng)濟(jì)增長(zhǎng)脫離正軌,,而美國(guó)經(jīng)濟(jì)復(fù)蘇是全球經(jīng)濟(jì)中唯一的亮點(diǎn)。

《財(cái)富》:那么,,如果美國(guó)決策者制定貿(mào)易保護(hù)主義政策,,防止貿(mào)易逆差大增,是不是合理的做法,?

佩蒂斯:眾所周知,,經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)家大衛(wèi)·李嘉圖認(rèn)為自由貿(mào)易促進(jìn)國(guó)民福利,但上世紀(jì)20和30年代,,有的國(guó)家并未創(chuàng)造國(guó)內(nèi)需求,,又試圖擴(kuò)大在全球需求中的比重,最后卻削減了整體需求,。假如降低本國(guó)的薪資或者讓本幣貶值,,全球總需求實(shí)際上會(huì)減少,該國(guó)在全球需求中所占比例相應(yīng)升高,。如果陷入這個(gè)怪圈,,上世紀(jì)30年代的悲劇就會(huì)重演。

最好的情況是,,世界各國(guó)聯(lián)合起來(lái)表示,,不會(huì)讓假設(shè)中的糟糕局面發(fā)生。不過(guò),這太愚蠢了,,我也沒(méi)有多少把握他們會(huì)這樣做,。

《財(cái)富》:中國(guó)政府試圖緩解經(jīng)濟(jì)著陸的影響,你怎么看這種嘗試,?

佩蒂斯:從抽象的角度看,,很容易判斷中國(guó)人的意圖。必須推動(dòng)與兩大重要目標(biāo)一致的改革,,頭號(hào)目標(biāo)是,,尋找新需求而且不能由負(fù)債催生,第二大目標(biāo)是,,降低債務(wù)水平,。

中國(guó)需要增加家庭收入占GDP的比例。這個(gè)比例已經(jīng)在緩慢上升,,但還得加快,。唯一的方法是將國(guó)有企業(yè)的財(cái)富轉(zhuǎn)移至家庭??杀娝苤?,這方面政治阻力很大。

《財(cái)富》:你所說(shuō)的將財(cái)富轉(zhuǎn)移給中國(guó)家庭,,具體要怎么做,?

佩蒂斯:理論上說(shuō)可以降低窮人的賦稅,但窮人納稅本來(lái)就少,,減稅起不到多大作用,。中國(guó)可以取消現(xiàn)行戶(hù)籍制度,讓貧窮的農(nóng)民工迅速脫貧,,因?yàn)槿∠青l(xiāng)戶(hù)籍差異以后,,農(nóng)民工能把孩子帶到城里上學(xué),找到收入更高的工作,。不過(guò),,這在政治上很難實(shí)現(xiàn)。

中國(guó)也可以推行企業(yè)私有化,,直接把股份轉(zhuǎn)向家庭轉(zhuǎn)移,。此前,奧地利就成功實(shí)現(xiàn)過(guò)這種嘗試,。

中國(guó)還可以將國(guó)有企業(yè)股份轉(zhuǎn)移到地方的社保系統(tǒng)。2015年3月山東省這樣做了,。問(wèn)題在于,,社保基金的信用很低,。

回顧2013年中共中央第十八屆三中全會(huì)公布的改革措施,,你會(huì)發(fā)現(xiàn)幾乎所有措施的目標(biāo)都是促進(jìn)消費(fèi),。但要真正實(shí)現(xiàn),就得減少某些方面的財(cái)富,,猜猜看會(huì)影響誰(shuí)的錢(qián)袋子吧,?所以,改革面臨的反對(duì)聲浪很高,。

經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)家顧問(wèn)一直在提糟糕的建議,,比如,要是能提高生產(chǎn)效率,,經(jīng)濟(jì)狀況就能改善,。實(shí)際上,中國(guó)的經(jīng)濟(jì)學(xué)家必須認(rèn)識(shí)到,,如果改革不能削減負(fù)債,,也不能增加財(cái)富,那就毫無(wú)意義,。道理就這么簡(jiǎn)單,。

即便中國(guó)的GDP增長(zhǎng)速度比預(yù)期水平高出0.1個(gè)百分點(diǎn),我們也不應(yīng)該高興,。因?yàn)?,只要增加債?wù)就可以把GDP增速拉高。

奧巴馬要是把芝加哥推倒重建,,就能把美國(guó)經(jīng)濟(jì)增速提高到7%,。但如此拉動(dòng)增長(zhǎng)愚不可及。(財(cái)富中文網(wǎng))

譯者:Pessy

校對(duì):夏林

Back in 2012, when oil prices were above $100 per barrel and the Chinese economy was growing at over 10% per year you’d be hard pressed to convince anyone that a commodity price collapse, fueled by a sputtering China, would be the event that finally brought the world back into recession.

Unless, of course, that person followed the writings of Michael Pettis, a former Wall Street trader and professor of finance at Peking University’s Guanghua School of Management. For years, Pettis has been warning of the growing imbalances in the Chinese economy, and he called the commodity price collapse as early as 2012.

Pettis argues that the Chinese economy is following the example of many countries that came before, like the Soviet Union following World War II, the Brazilian economy in the 1970s, and Japan in the 1980s. In each of these cases, national governments put forward policies that artificially boosted investment and suppressed consumption, policies that led to a fast buildup of growth and large trade surpluses. But eventually these imbalances go into reverse, and that is what is happening now. Fortune reached out to Pettis to get his take on what will happen next in China, and how it will affect the U.S. economy. The interview has been edited for length and clarity.

Fortune: At what point did you recognize that China’s growth model was unsustainable?

Michael Pettis: Pretty early on—by 2006, it was obvious.

What made you realize that China’s growth model was like the failed experiments in places like Brazil?

[Economist] Alexander Gerschenkron argues that there are two fundamental parts to an investment-led boom. First, you have to force up the savings rate, which you do by constraining growth in household consumption. And next you have to direct the investment process. But if you look at all the investment growth miracles, they all did that.

One of the things that really struck me was that during the miracle periods, at first when growth rates are really high, everyone is shocked. And then during the adjustment period, it slows so quickly, we’re all shocked. There’s been no exceptions. It’s always like that. We’re shocked on the way up and shocked on the way down.

This happens to individual companies, too. Take a company like Enron, which is a very common story. Before Enron fell apart, it was just growing spectacularly. I think it was the most admired company in America eight out of 10 years before it went under. When a company or country has an inverted balance sheet [i.e. one with an asset structure that doesn’t hedge bets, but amplifies them] it’s really like you have your correct balance sheet with a very speculative overlay on top of it. All you’re doing is exacerbating underlying conditions.

It’s like if you invest in the stock market, but you margin write it to the hilt. If the market goes up, you make more money than anybody else, and you and everyone else start to think you’re a genius. And when the market goes down, you get wiped out. And it seemed to me that these economies were doing something very similar. They were growing much more quickly than we had any right to expect. And then suddenly they were slowing much more quickly than anyone believed possible.

For years, you have been predicting a collapse in commodity prices. Most economists don’t see the crash infecting large economies like the United States. Why are they wrong?

In places like China and Germany, we’re seeing high income inequality while the household share of GDP is quite low. The inequality has the same impact. It pushes up the savings rate because the rich save more than ordinary people. Is that good or bad? Supply siders tell us that it’s always good to increase the savings rate. Keynsians will tell us no, we have to increase demand.

The truth is they are wrong, or that they are both right only under very specific conditions.

For much of the 19th century, there was a huge “problem” of income inequality in England, and so the savings rate was too high. But you had … the United States, which was credible and urgently needed excess savings from England to fund productive investments. That’s where the excess savings went, and the English got richer, and we got richer.

If you have productive investment that’s credible and that’s being constrained by the lack of savings, then income inequality is actually good for the economy. But if you don’t, then you have the problems that you saw in the 1930s, where excess savings forced down the savings rate in the middle class by forcing up consumption. The savings go into speculative markets. Stock markets go up, real estate goes up, we all feel richer, just like during the real estate bubble. But once that game stops because of debt, then you still have to balance savings and investment. But because nobody is investing, then you’ve got to bring savings down. And the way you bring savings down is firing workers.

And that’s what we’re seeing around the globe, with job losses beginning in the commodity sector. I think Larry Summers is right in saying that the globe is starved for demand.

You see this as the beginning of a long period of slow global growth?

Yes, we’re in a period of weak global growth, in which trade is going to get worse. And we’re going to see a wave of sovereign defaults. What really worries me is that the Europeans have been incredibly irresponsible. The huge German problems, which first bankrupted Europe, were then forced abroad. And China also has a huge surplus, Japan has and needs a rising surplus. Who’s going to absorb it? In the last few years it has been the metal producers and the energy producers—their trade deficits grew. But they can’t do that anymore. In fact, Brazil will run a surplus this year from a deficit last year. So something’s gotta happen. And arithmetically, only two things can happen: either the surpluses of Europe and China go down, or somebody else’s deficit has to go up. And that country is always the most open economy that allows capital inflows: The United States, Canada, Australia, and the U.K. And my really big concern is that we’re going to see a soaring trade deficit in the U.S. which could derail the U.S. economy, which is the only bright spot right now.

Would it be rational for American policy makers to enact protectionist policies to prevent a soaring trade deficit?

We all know from [economist David] Ricardo that free trade is wealth enhancing, but in the 1920s and 1930s, when countries, rather than create domestic demand, tried to expand their share of global demand, they actually ended up reducing overall demand. If you lower wages or depreciate your currency, total global demand actually goes down but you get a bigger share of global demand. And when you get caught up in that spiral, you get yourself caught up in what happened in the 1930s.

The best thing would be for the world to get together and say we can’t allow this to happen, it would be incredibly stupid. But I’m not confident that this will happen.

How do you feel about the Chinese government’s attempt to soften the landing?

From an abstract point of view, it’s easy to tell the Chinese what to do. You must put forward reforms that are consistent with the two most important objectives. Objective No. 1 has to be to find a new source of demand that doesn’t come from debt, and objective No. 2 is to bring debt levels down.

They need to increase the household share of GDP. It’s rising slowly, but they need to speed it up, and the only way to do that is to transfer wealth from the state sector. But as you know, politically, that is really tough.

How do you practically transfer wealth to Chinese households?

In principle, you could cut taxes on the poor, but they don’t pay a lot of taxes so that’s not going to help much. You could eliminate the hukou system. That would make poor migrants immediately richer because now they can send their kids to school and find better paying jobs. That’s really politically tough to do.

You could privatize corporations and simply give the shares to households, as they did successfully in Austria.

You could transfer ownership shares to the local social safety net. Shandong province did that in March. The problem is that the pension fund has very low credibility.

If you look at the 3rd plenum reforms in 2013, almost all of them aim to [boost consumption] But to actually accomplish these goals, you have to reduce somebody’s wealth, and guess whose wealth it is? The government and the wealthy. So there’s a lot of opposition.

The economists keep giving the administration terrible advice, like if you improve the efficiency of, say the peanut business, that’s going to make a difference. They have to recognize that reforms that don’t reduce debt or increase household wealth are simply not going to matter. And that’s the end of the story.

If GDP growth is 1/10th of a point higher than expected, instead of applauding, we should be groaning. You can get any level of growth you want as long as you increase debt. Obama could get 7% growth if he wanted, if he tore Chicago to the ground and rebuilt it. It’s just a stupid way of getting growth.

掃描二維碼下載財(cái)富APP